Google

The Deipnosophist

Where the science of investing becomes an art of living

My Photo
Name:
Location: Summerlin, Nevada, United States

A private investor for 20+ years, I manage private portfolios and write about investing. You can read my market musings on three different sites: 1) The Deipnosophist, dedicated to teaching the market's processes and mechanics; 2) Investment Poetry, a subscription site dedicated to real time investment recommendations; and 3) Seeking Alpha, a combination of the other two sites with a mix of reprints from this site and all-original content. See you here, there, or the other site!

16 May 2008

Google's reply

Hal Varian, Google's Chief Economist, 'replies' to my off-handed comment re "Google's reliance on algorithms rather than humans [that] irritates many of their clients and even their advertisers..."

All of the major search engines use auctions to price ads. The reason is simple: there are millions of keywords that need to be priced and it would be impossible to set all those prices by hand.

Using an auction removes the burden of having to do this: the prices are determined by the auction participants. These auctions run every time a user enters a query, so they always reflect the current values that advertisers place on keywords.

The outcome of the ad auction is efficient in the sense that the available ad slots are awarded to those who value them mostly highly. The outcome is also equitable in that the price an advertiser has to pay is determined by the other advertisers -- those with whom it has to compete for slots.

But how do they actually work? There are several steps in the process.
1) Each advertiser enters a list of keywords, ads, and bids.
2) When a user enters a query, Google compiles a list of all the ads whose keywords match that query.
3) The list of ads is then ordered based on the bids and the
Ad Quality Scores, which measure the relevance of the ad to the user.
4) The highest ranked ad is displayed in the most prominent position, the second highest ranked ad gets the second most prominent position, and so on.
5) If the user clicks on an ad, the advertiser is charged a price that depends on the bid and Quality Score of the advertiser below it. The price charged is the minimum necessary to retain the advertiser's position in the list.

A simple example is when all ads have the same Quality Score. In this case, the ads will be ranked by bids and the price an advertiser pays per click will just be the bid of advertiser below it in the ranking. Hence the amount that advertisers pay is no more than what they bid and typically less.

In the general case, where ad qualities differ, the price an advertiser pays for a click will depend on its Quality Score relative to the quality of the ad below it in the auction. Roughly speaking, an ad that has twice the quality of another ad will tend to get about twice as many clicks, and will only have to pay half as much per click as the competing ad.

Where does this Ad Quality Score come from? It was originally determined by historical click through rates but has been refined over the years using sophisticated statistical models. Using ad quality as a factor in ranking ads provides strong incentives to advertisers to make sure that they provide relevant ads to end users.

There are many additional tweaks on top of this basic design. For example, Google actually runs two auctions: one for ads at the top of the page, and one for ads on the side of the page. Only ads with particularly high quality are eligible to compete in the top-ad auction. Ads that have particularly low quality may be disabled, and not shown at all. Advertisers also can set and adjust their daily and monthly budget so as to cap their maximum spend.

But the essential structure is that outlined above: advertisers bid for position and pay just enough to beat their runner-up. Prices for keywords are, ultimately, determined by the advertisers.


Yes, all true... for as far as it goes. The problems, if you want to call them that, begin with the reserve pricing for AdWords. Any reader who participates in art auctions has familiarity with reserve pricing; in essence, the artist (or auction house, etc) establishes a minimum for bids that, if not met, he or she reserves the option to remove the item from auction. Google's policy of reserve pricing places human interference in the auction process at the get-go, which alloys the purity of the auction process

But human intervention at Google does not end there. Consider, for example, that Google sales reps instruct possible advertisers that his or her selected AdWord is inappropriate for their needs; such as when a sales rep tells one advertiser that his word selections, "poker" and "online poker" are inappropriate AdWords for his book, a primer on online poker. Hmm.

Unfortunately, Google's culture worsens the matter. Its employees have become comfortable working within the shroud that veils the Googleplex; in fact, so comfortable that they have lost the ability to relate to their customers, clients, vendors, prospects, and shareholders. Company employees pay homage to their nerdiness via recusing themselves from almost all human contact. (Try contacting someone at the firm, anyone, to see first-hand what I mean.)

I admit the firm's collected and collective intelligence helps to create their continued successes, but it also represents a risk that could derail the firm. One the company muckey-mucks should recognize. Of course, this type of risk always is and will be; a double-edged sword; yin and yang, and all that.

Full Disclosure: Long Google/GOOG.
-- David M Gordon / The Deipnosophist

Labels: , ,

who's online